ISET

ISET Economist Blog

A blog about economics in the South Caucasus.

Can Georgia Develop a Knowledge-Based Economy?

A few weeks ago, the Israeli ambassador His Excellency Yuval Fuchs delivered a speech at ISET, explaining the amazing transformation of Israel from what essentially was an agricultural state into what many economists call a knowledge economy. The ambassador reported that in his youth the foremost product Israel was known for were oranges. In the last thirty years, however, Israel created a high-tech sector that can compete (and in many aspects surpasses) the high-tech industries of the United States and Europe. Over 60 Israeli companies are listed in the US technology stock exchange NASDAQ, more than of any other foreign country, and many marvelous innovations, like Google’s “auto suggest” function or the RSA encryption technology, can be attributed to Israeli companies. The ambassador practically demonstrated the innovativeness of the Israeli economy by bringing his presentation slides saved on a smart card that could be kept in his wallet like a bank card. Moreover, he brought some Russian-language copies of Dan Senor and Saul Singer’s 2009 book “Start-Up Nation” for the ISET library, a book that describes how the Israeli economy became a cradle of innovations (if somebody is interested to know more about this story, they can come to the ISET library and read it there).

While Israel’s success may have to do with some special factors, in particular the immigration of smart people from post-soviet countries and the role of the Israeli army, Fuchs believes that also Georgia could develop a high-tech sector. In some respects, Georgia today is not that much different from how Israel was 30 years ago. The most striking similarity is, as mentioned before, the important role of agriculture in Israel until the end of the 1970s and in Georgia today.


WHAT MAKES A KNOWLEDGE ECONOMY?

The three traditional economic sectors are agriculture (the “primary sector”), manufacturing (the “secondary sector”), and services (the “tertiary sector”). One can characterize these sectors by their main input factors. The primary sector makes use of land and natural resources, the secondary sector mainly requires capital, and the tertiary sector draws on a nation’s labor force. The knowledge economy, sometimes called the “quaternary sector” of an economy, is based on human capital, i.e. education, knowledge, and other intellectual inputs.

A prudent economic policy can indeed foster the development of a knowledge economy, as shown by several examples. In 1996, Costa Rica, a small country with a population of 4.3 million people, beat Brazil, Chile, Indonesia, Mexico, the Philippines, and Thailand in a competition to attract Intel’s investment of $300 million for building a semiconductor assembly and development plant. Intel’s choice was based on many factors, like political and economic stability, taxes, and so forth, but the decisive aspect was Costa Rica’s high-skilled labor force. For most of the time after the Second World War, Costa Rica was an agrarian country, exporting coffee, bananas and pineapples. Yet while the economy was still focused on agriculture, after the restoration of democracy in 1948 it invested heavily in its education system. Spanish-speaking Costa Rica adopted a bi-lingual English-Spanish curriculum, and already in 1988, when personal computers were far from being standard equipment in offices and households, they introduced computers at public schools. Today, Costa Rica still produces bananas and pineapples, but its main export product are computer chips (similar to Israel, that still grows oranges and kiwis, but they do not account for a significant share of their produce anymore).

There are other examples that are closer to Georgia’s situation. Since the turn of the millennium, the governments of Poland, Bulgaria, Slovakia, and the Baltic countries worked out strategic plans for promoting their knowledge sectors. Typically, these plans have time horizons of 10 to 15 years, which is a rather short time if one intends to bring about fundamental changes in the economic structure of a country. For example, “Success Estonia 2014” was presented in 2002 and primarily aims to dovetail university research with research done in private companies. “Public-private” research is advantageous in as it incentivizes university professors to work in areas that have economic potential, making it more likely that discoveries can be transformed into marketable products and economic growth. Moreover, aligning public and private research is essentially an adjustment of public research agendas to private needs, hence it is an indirect way of subsidizing research in companies. But also universities can profit from a close cooperation with the private sector. It allows their students to work with companies while still being enrolled, fostering a smooth integration of graduates into the labor market, and of course it provides private funding for university research. In addition, students do not lose sight of potential applications of their skills. While it is nice for a nation to have experts in abstract fields without practical applications, for a society struck with poverty it may be more desirable if universities create entrepreneurs and start-ups.

The follow-up plan, called “Knowledge-based Estonia 2014-2020”, puts emphasis on the removal of bottlenecks that prevent the transformation of scientific potential into economic growth. The Russian “Innovation Strategy 2020” is another such transition plan, and also Singapore replaced its “catching up” strategy with a knowledge agenda. To that end, Singapore’s government established an “Economic Review Committee” which is coordinating the various efforts to promote the knowledge sector.

 

Ramat Gan, a suburb of Tel Aviv. In the 1970s, Israel was mainly an exporter of Oranges and other agricultural goods. Today it has an economy that competes in the high-tech sector with the US and Europe. Photo: Wikimedia Commons.

Ramat Gan, a suburb of Tel Aviv. In the 1970s, Israel was mainly an exporter of Oranges and other agricultural goods. Today it has an economy that competes in the high-tech sector with the US and Europe. Photo: Wikimedia Commons.


CAVEATS

While Costa Rica shows how one can steer economic development towards knowledge industries, it also shows that this usually takes plenty of time. A knowledge economy cannot be established in a fortnight, but requires long-run investments in education and research institutions, possibly for decades. And here Georgia has obvious deficits. When teachers and professors belong to the worst-paid group in the labor force, there is no way how an economy could develop a strong knowledge sector. For a knowledge economy to pick up, schools and universities must recruit its teaching personnel from the best students of each cohort. Yet in Georgia, no sane person wants to become a teacher. In contrast, in a country like Germany the average salary of teachers for the last three years of high-school (a time where many Georgian pupils do not attend school anymore, because it is considered useless) is 50% higher than the average salary of the country (after 15 years of service). In Switzerland, at the end of their careers teachers earn double the average salary. And this makes a lot of sense. You can only expect to have good pupils and students if you have good teachers (we recommend to have a look at the article “Like Teacher, Like Son” by Eric Livny and Giorgi Tsutskiridze).

Another big question is whether one can directly move to a knowledge-based economy if almost 60% of people are still employed in agriculture. Is it not necessary to first have an industrial and a service stage before a knowledge economy can be created?

The debate is reminiscent to the question whether the Proletarian Revolution could be successful in Russia of 1917, which at that time was largely an agricultural society, rather than in the more industrialized countries of Western Europe. While Stalin demonstrated that, starting with an agricultural economy, one can develop heavy industry and even the nuclear bomb by means of coercion, command economy, and forced labor, it is very unclear whether the intermediate stages can be left out when moving towards a knowledge-based economy. Having a competitive industrial or service sector is extremely useful if one wants to become a knowledge leader in a field, in particular if the university system is dovetailed with private research and development. If a promising discovery is made at an American University, a company to buy the patent and develop a marketable product is nearby. In Georgia, on the other hand, the patent would have to be sold to a foreign company, due to a lack of local firms that could transform it into a sellable product. Then the discovery would generate much less profit for the society as in America.

However, many development economists believe that it is possible to skip certain development stages. This so-called “leapfrogging theory” is supported by some evidence, e.g. countries that moved directly from a situation without any telephones to mobile telephone networks, leaving out the stage of landline telephones.

The recipe for developing a knowledge sector, namely massive upgrading of the education system, is a strategic necessity for any development to take place in Georgia. Therefore, the risk of pursuing a knowledge agenda is limited. And, if we are lucky, some leapfrogging will take place in the Caucasus.

Rate this blog entry:
4 Comments

Related Posts

Comments

 
Guest - Till on ხუთშაბათი, 24 აპრილი 2014 17:21

My understanding is that in Western countries, teachers and schools only account for about a third of learning outcomes. Kids' home environment accounts for two thirds. This may explain the (small minority) of highly educated Georgians emerging from Georgia's dysfunctional 1990s education system.

So maybe you need well-educated parents before you can have well-educated kinds? This would make improvements in the status quo even slower.

Also, high teacher salaries by themselves will not help. If not accompanied by other factors, they may only attract the lazy, and could even keep very smart people in villages rather than incentivizing them to move into the cities, where the future lies. There's a trade-off between having your best and brightest in front of blackboards, and having them in the private sector creating innovation and jobs.

My understanding is that in Western countries, teachers and schools only account for about a third of learning outcomes. Kids' home environment accounts for two thirds. This may explain the (small minority) of highly educated Georgians emerging from Georgia's dysfunctional 1990s education system. So maybe you need well-educated parents before you can have well-educated kinds? This would make improvements in the status quo even slower. Also, high teacher salaries by themselves will not help. If not accompanied by other factors, they may only attract the lazy, and could even keep very smart people in villages rather than incentivizing them to move into the cities, where the future lies. There's a trade-off between having your best and brightest in front of blackboards, and having them in the private sector creating innovation and jobs.
Guest - Florian Biermann on ხუთშაბათი, 24 აპრილი 2014 21:21

Good salaries are not a sufficient but a necessary condition for having good teachers and professors.

There is no doubt that for any development to happen in a modern society, it is necessary to pay people in the educational sector well. You need to compensate the huge investments professors and teachers made in their human capital. Otherwise, the human capital necessary to be a decent professor (or teacher) will simply not be accumulated.

Some professors in Georgia are paid about 230 lari per month (about $130), and for teachers the situation is even worse. You can easily make more money with very simple jobs, like guard or doorman, without any investment in your human capital. Under such conditions, just idealists or people without alternatives are then willing to work in schools and universities -- but there are just few idealists around, and you do not want those who have no alternatives.

The ridiculously low payment of teachers and professors in Georgia is a relic of Soviet times and, 25 years after the end of the Soviet Union, should really have come to an end. The fact that teachers and many professors are still paid so badly shows that Georgian politics throughout the different eras of the last 25 years failed to understand what the most important source of wealth is for a country like Georgia.

The trade-off you are speaking about does not exist in reality. Without smart people at schools and universities, there will also be no experts that can create jobs in companies. You need to have the best people in the education system in order to satisfy the human capital needs of the economy. I do not think that there is any country in the world where, from a social point of view, too many people go to universities and too few to the private sector. Almost everywhere, it is difficult for universities to compete with private employers, and from a social point of view, in most countries are arguably too few smart people in the education sector.

Good salaries are not a sufficient but a necessary condition for having good teachers and professors. There is no doubt that for any development to happen in a modern society, it is necessary to pay people in the educational sector well. You need to compensate the huge investments professors and teachers made in their human capital. Otherwise, the human capital necessary to be a decent professor (or teacher) will simply not be accumulated. Some professors in Georgia are paid about 230 lari per month (about $130), and for teachers the situation is even worse. You can easily make more money with very simple jobs, like guard or doorman, without any investment in your human capital. Under such conditions, just idealists or people without alternatives are then willing to work in schools and universities -- but there are just few idealists around, and you do not want those who have no alternatives. The ridiculously low payment of teachers and professors in Georgia is a relic of Soviet times and, 25 years after the end of the Soviet Union, should really have come to an end. The fact that teachers and many professors are still paid so badly shows that Georgian politics throughout the different eras of the last 25 years failed to understand what the most important source of wealth is for a country like Georgia. The trade-off you are speaking about does not exist in reality. Without smart people at schools and universities, there will also be no experts that can create jobs in companies. You need to have the best people in the education system in order to satisfy the human capital needs of the economy. I do not think that there is any country in the world where, from a social point of view, too many people go to universities and too few to the private sector. Almost everywhere, it is difficult for universities to compete with private employers, and from a social point of view, in most countries are arguably too few smart people in the education sector.
Guest - Eric Livny on ხუთშაბათი, 24 აპრილი 2014 22:11

Florian, I take most of points but don't put the blame for low salaries in the education system on the Soviet Union. Teachers and professors were a privileged caste back in the Soviet time. Both in term of income and social status. The irony of histrory is that the educated class, the literati of the Soviet Union have been the greatest losers in the upheaval they brought upon their countries in late 80s and early 90s. Nobody needed them in a country (or rather countries) ruled by thugs, former party bosses, and the new rich.

Florian, I take most of points but don't put the blame for low salaries in the education system on the Soviet Union. Teachers and professors were a privileged caste back in the Soviet time. Both in term of income and social status. The irony of histrory is that the educated class, the literati of the Soviet Union have been the greatest losers in the upheaval they brought upon their countries in late 80s and early 90s. Nobody needed them in a country (or rather countries) ruled by thugs, former party bosses, and the new rich.
Guest - Florian Biermann on ხუთშაბათი, 24 აპრილი 2014 22:17

This is surprising news for me. I thought that, in line with the Marxian "labor theory of value", the intelligentsia was paid very badly in communist countries. I have a friend who was teacher in the Soviet Union, teaching mainly steel workers from Rustavi. He told me that the steel workers were making fun of him because they made much more money as he did. This also reduced their motivation to learn anything from him. Anyway, perhaps my information is wrong, or the picture is not that clear...

This is surprising news for me. I thought that, in line with the Marxian "labor theory of value", the intelligentsia was paid very badly in communist countries. I have a friend who was teacher in the Soviet Union, teaching mainly steel workers from Rustavi. He told me that the steel workers were making fun of him because they made much more money as he did. This also reduced their motivation to learn anything from him. Anyway, perhaps my information is wrong, or the picture is not that clear...
Already Registered? Login Here
Register
Guest
შაბათი, 23 ნოემბერი 2024

Captcha Image

Our Partners