ISET

ISET Economist Blog

A blog about economics in the South Caucasus.

Economic Growth and Income Inequality in Georgia

Poverty and income inequality are two of the top concerns for the newly elected Georgian government. Indeed, despite impressive growth performance (annual growth rates have averaged more than 6% since 2005), Georgia remains a poor country. Once the wealthiest Soviet republic, Georgia fell far behind others (except, perhaps, Tajikistan, Kyrgyzstan and Moldova) on almost any parameter of wellbeing. Adjusted for purchasing power parity, Georgia’s annual income per capita in 2011 was in the $5,400-5,800 ballpark (very similar to the resource-poor Armenia). Moreover, the “median” Georgian, as opposed to the “average” Georgian, is much poorer than suggested by the per capita income estimate. Like any average measure, the income per capita figure masks inequality in the distribution of income, and Georgia is much less equal compared to all ex-Soviet peers (with the possible exception of Russia).

An argument is advanced by some economists that it is perfectly reasonable to expect inequality levels to increase as a country starts to develop from very low levels of productivity, as is presumably the case in Georgia. These arguments find support in a theory that was popularized by Simon Kuznets in the 1950s. Accordingly, market forces tend to bring about higher levels of income inequality at an early stage of development; yet, after a certain level of average income is achieved, inequality would decrease.

The logic behind this inverse U-shaped relationship (“the Kuznets curve”) is based on the British model of modernization and industrialization, as follows:

  • Initially, smallholder farmers are evicted from their property through a process of land consolidation and technological progress in agriculture. The result is enrichment of landed aristocracy (whose ‘savings’ could be used to finance investment in capital), horrific poverty among landless peasantry and rapid urbanization. Oversupplied with low skill labor, the cities welcome rural migrants into the fast-growing class of urban poor barely surviving on a subsistence wage. The accumulation of capital increases labor productivity, yet as long as rural migration continues, wages remain depressed, leading to the emergence of an enormous income gap between the owners of land and capital, on the one hand, and the rest.
  • Once the pace of urbanization slows down, labor begins to claim – and receives – a larger share of the pie. From that point on, nations experience greater democratization, improvement of education and healthcare systems, and the rise of the welfare state. Growth continues, yet productivity gains begin to trickle down. Hence the logic behind the downward sloping portion of the Kuznets curve.

While logical, this theory has lost its appeal after the 1960s. Not in the least because an entire group of countries constituting the so-called “East Asian Miracle” – Hong Kong, Indonesia, Japan, South Korea, Malaysia, Singapore, Taiwan and Thailand – demonstrated the possibility of inclusive growth. In his influential article, “Some Lessons from the East Asian Miracle” (1996), Joseph Stiglitz points out that equality and growth reinforced each other in East Asia: “High rates of growth provided the resources that could be used to promote equality, just as high equality helped sustain the high rates of growth”. In Korea, Japan and Taiwan, he writes:

Land reforms were important in the initial stages of development. These had three effects: they increased rural productivity and income and resulted in increased savings; higher income provided the domestic demand that was important in these economies before export markets expanded; and the redistribution of income contributed to political stability, an important factor in creating a good environment for domestic and foreign investment.”

The emphasis on inclusivity was important in later stages of development as well. Higher wages made workers more satisfied, more productive and more willing to cooperate with the firms. Policies that restricted real estate speculation made housing more affordable and helped reduce demands for higher wages. Education policies ensuring universal literacy promoted both greater equity and productivity.

Now, while the East Asian Miracle demonstrates the possibility (and the benefits) of inclusive modernization and industrialization, the main lesson learned from the recent Georgian experience is this: in the 21st century a developing nation cannot achieve and sustain growth while ignoring concerns for equity. Near universal literacy, access to information and social networks provide the poor with political mobilization possibilities that were unthinkable in 18th century Britain. Rural development and redistribution policies may come at a significant cost to the economy in the short run, yet they are essential for political stability. Without political stability no investment, domestic or foreign, will take place.

To summarize, there is nothing “reasonable” or “good” about the wide and persistent income inequality that hit Georgia in the post-independence period. Whatever its virtues, the Kuznets curve hypothesis is utterly irrelevant for any discussion of the Georgian experience. If anything, the Georgian nation became poor and highly unequal because it went through a process of rapid dis-investment and de-industrialization. It was forced to shut down industrial plants, sending scrap metal abroad and workers into subsistence farming or early retirement. Thanks to moderate climate and soil conditions, hunger has never become an issue, yet inequality and associated political pressures rapidly reached catastrophic dimensions, unleashing cycles of violence, undermining the political order and the prospects of economic growth.

Rate this blog entry:
4 Comments

Comments

 
Guest - Nika on სამშაბათი, 11 დეკემბერი 2012 02:18

mokled ra mainteresebs chvenma axalma mtavrobam sityvaze rom gaxsnas ramdenime qarxana ar vici romel sferoshi(movifiqrebt mere) da ara mogebis misagebad aramed piriqit bevri samushaob adgili sheqmnas da tundac sacarmo cagebaze mushaobdes (amis resursi gvaqvs bidzina(jmotobas tu daicyebs shevcvlit)). mokled carmoeba gvijdeba dzviri, fasi unda gvqondes chinelebivit. sabolood iqneb chvenc viscavlot saqmis keteba da ayvavdes qveyana. magram radganac ese martivia es ambavi albat sadmee gaaketebdnen da rasebobs realuri magaliti rame msgavsis? anu idea imashia ro tu saqartveloshi amjamad 100 biznesia momgebiani, saqartveloshi iqneba 200 biznesi romlisganac 100 camgebiania magram cagebashi ar vgulisxmob miliardebs. (tan realurad importze tu iqneba saubari uketesi iqneba iqeb valebidanac amodzvres samshoblo). vinme kargi ekonomistis azri mainteresebs

mokled ra mainteresebs chvenma axalma mtavrobam sityvaze rom gaxsnas ramdenime qarxana ar vici romel sferoshi(movifiqrebt mere) da ara mogebis misagebad aramed piriqit bevri samushaob adgili sheqmnas da tundac sacarmo cagebaze mushaobdes (amis resursi gvaqvs bidzina(jmotobas tu daicyebs shevcvlit)). mokled carmoeba gvijdeba dzviri, fasi unda gvqondes chinelebivit. sabolood iqneb chvenc viscavlot saqmis keteba da ayvavdes qveyana. magram radganac ese martivia es ambavi albat sadmee gaaketebdnen da rasebobs realuri magaliti rame msgavsis? anu idea imashia ro tu saqartveloshi amjamad 100 biznesia momgebiani, saqartveloshi iqneba 200 biznesi romlisganac 100 camgebiania magram cagebashi ar vgulisxmob miliardebs. (tan realurad importze tu iqneba saubari uketesi iqneba iqeb valebidanac amodzvres samshoblo). vinme kargi ekonomistis azri mainteresebs
Guest - Juan Echanove on სამშაბათი, 11 დეკემბერი 2012 20:20

Excellent analysis, indeed, which I largely endorse.

Just an important issue to mention: for reaching economies of scale in agriculture, what is needed is to consolidate production , which is not exactly the same as ' to consolidate land'. Land is just one factor of production (and actually land size is not the single most significant element to ensure production...not in modern agriculture anymore!...soil quality, technologies, aces to water are much more significant factors to increase yields)


Actually, land is the most difficult production factor to 'consolidate' (I.e. increase by aggregation) due to (a) cultural factors (and this not only applies to post soviet countries...every farmer in the world wants to have his/her very own parcel of land belonging only to him!) , (b) practical factors (you need a sophisticated land market in place, which will only be available in Georgia once there is cash in the countryside flowing, so some farmers can actually acquire the land) (c) economic factors; When the farmer is not owning the land he works, but it belongs to some coop or other similar structure, efficiency goes down (there is overwhelming evidence of this) because he will tend to think that he is not personal responsible for the production any more -he actually become an 'employee' , not an small business men.It is land what makes a farmer an farmer. he looses the land, he is not farmer anymore.

But, the good news is that all other means of production can be consolidated...and the farmer will remaining a farmer! I.ee.g. (1) joint acquisition of inputs (seeds, fertilizers, feed,,,,,,) or services (mechanization, artificial insemination, training..) or 2) joint commercialisation. Doing the first, farmers reduce production costs, doing the second, farmers increase quality and quantity of production, and thus, income.

But the button line of the article is obvious: Without equity high rates of growth are just impossible to maintain in the long run.And equity, in Georgia, means largely investing in the half of the population which is not in the market economy and relays only in the little garden production of the plot to survive.

This is all to say that the ENPARD will NOT promote production coops, but service and marketing coops....which a very significant distinction

Juan Echanove

Excellent analysis, indeed, which I largely endorse. Just an important issue to mention: for reaching economies of scale in agriculture, what is needed is to consolidate production , which is not exactly the same as ' to consolidate land'. Land is just one factor of production (and actually land size is not the single most significant element to ensure production...not in modern agriculture anymore!...soil quality, technologies, aces to water are much more significant factors to increase yields) Actually, land is the most difficult production factor to 'consolidate' (I.e. increase by aggregation) due to (a) cultural factors (and this not only applies to post soviet countries...every farmer in the world wants to have his/her very own parcel of land belonging only to him!) , (b) practical factors (you need a sophisticated land market in place, which will only be available in Georgia once there is cash in the countryside flowing, so some farmers can actually acquire the land) (c) economic factors; When the farmer is not owning the land he works, but it belongs to some coop or other similar structure, efficiency goes down (there is overwhelming evidence of this) because he will tend to think that he is not personal responsible for the production any more -he actually become an 'employee' , not an small business men.It is land what makes a farmer an farmer. he looses the land, he is not farmer anymore. But, the good news is that all other means of production can be consolidated...and the farmer will remaining a farmer! I.ee.g. (1) joint acquisition of inputs (seeds, fertilizers, feed,,,,,,) or services (mechanization, artificial insemination, training..) or 2) joint commercialisation. Doing the first, farmers reduce production costs, doing the second, farmers increase quality and quantity of production, and thus, income. But the button line of the article is obvious: Without equity high rates of growth are just impossible to maintain in the long run.And equity, in Georgia, means largely investing in the half of the population which is not in the market economy and relays only in the little garden production of the plot to survive. This is all to say that the ENPARD will NOT promote production coops, but service and marketing coops....which a very significant distinction Juan Echanove
Guest - Eric on ოთხშაბათი, 12 დეკემბერი 2012 16:03

Juan, many thanks for your comment. I am sorry to have removed the land consolidation part to this new blog post http://www.iset.ge/blog/?p=1089.

Am glad the emphasis in ENPARD is on service and marketing coops. The farmers may themselves eventually decide that it makes sense for them to consolidation production, but cooperation in the procurement of inputs, services and the marketing of their products would be a great step forward, in terms of productivity AND the building of mutual trust. The latter would be of course important for any deeper consolidation...

Juan, many thanks for your comment. I am sorry to have removed the land consolidation part to this new blog post http://www.iset.ge/blog/?p=1089. Am glad the emphasis in ENPARD is on service and marketing coops. The farmers may themselves eventually decide that it makes sense for them to consolidation production, but cooperation in the procurement of inputs, services and the marketing of their products would be a great step forward, in terms of productivity AND the building of mutual trust. The latter would be of course important for any deeper consolidation...
Guest - Irakli Gegeshidze, Ph.D. on ოთხშაბათი, 02 იანვარი 2013 22:39

" As we think about how to strengthen our economy, it is imperative that we not succumb to GDP fetishism. We've seen that GDP is not a good measure of economic performance; it doesn't reflect accurately changes in the standart of living, broadly defined, of most citizens, and it doesn't tell us whether the growth we experience is sustainable." Joseph E. Stiglitz, "The Price of Inequality". What means average 6% of GDP growth in Georgia and what is the quality and equality of those 6%? The economic situation in countries like our must be measure with a little bit differente dimension. What kind? we need to rethink about this issue toghether - good arbitre is half of the game!

" As we think about how to strengthen our economy, it is imperative that we not succumb to GDP fetishism. We've seen that GDP is not a good measure of economic performance; it doesn't reflect accurately changes in the standart of living, broadly defined, of most citizens, and it doesn't tell us whether the growth we experience is sustainable." Joseph E. Stiglitz, "The Price of Inequality". What means average 6% of GDP growth in Georgia and what is the quality and equality of those 6%? The economic situation in countries like our must be measure with a little bit differente dimension. What kind? we need to rethink about this issue toghether - good arbitre is half of the game!
Already Registered? Login Here
Register
Guest
შაბათი, 23 ნოემბერი 2024

Captcha Image

Our Partners