ISET

ISET Economist Blog

A blog about economics in the South Caucasus.

Why Nations Fail

Over the winter holidays, I had the leisure to read the book “Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty” by MIT economist Daron Acemoglu and Harvard political scientist James A. Robinson (Crown Business 2012, 544 pages, Hardcover $20.00). Both authors are very eminent – one would not be surprised if Acemoglu, a Turkish-born Armenian and the most frequently cited contemporary economist, would receive the Nobel Prize in economics somewhere down the road.

After reading the book, I was rather disappointed, because it appeared to me as if its message bordered on triviality. Didn’t the authors just say that dictators who oppress and exploit their populations are bad, while inclusive democracies that abide by the rule of law are good?

Well, the longer I think about their theory, the more I find it appealing, in particular as I can nicely connect it with my experiences as an economist living in Georgia.

 

... while other societies are rich? (Source: Wikimedia Commons)

... while other societies are rich? (Source: Wikimedia Commons)

 

CREATIVE DESTRUCTION

Acemoglu and Robinson draw on an idea put forward by Joseph Schumpeter (1883-1950). According to Schumpeter, the driving force behind economic progress is what he calls “creative destruction”, namely the replacement of old business models by new ones, of old products by new products, and of old professions by new professions. Instead of emphasizing the positive, constructive role of entrepreneurs (“building up a business”), he focuses on the fact that new developments in the economy usually go at the expense of existing sectors and industries. Yet Schumpeter believes that this destruction is at the core of economic progress, and that without it there would be just stagnation and incrustation. Indeed, it is easy to find examples for the beneficial role of creative destruction. For instance, at the beginning of the 20th century, entrepreneurs producing pneumatic tires have replaced those who made wooden wheels, but the frequent English name “Wright” indicates that wheelwright was an important profession in the past. Despite the destruction of the wheelwright profession, everybody would agree that the replacement of wooden wheels by pneumatic tires was part of the economic progress of humankind.

As a matter of fact, those who control the economy are usually also politically powerful. Yet if this is so, Acemoglu and Robinson ask, why should economic-political rulers allow creative destruction to happen, as this destruction threatens the very basis of their economic and political power? And indeed, as they show, creative destruction was and is frequently suppressed by those who possess power.

Supported by a plethora of interesting, sometimes curious and funny examples, the authors interpret economic history as a fight between those who want to preserve existing “modes of production” (to use a Marxian term) against those who come up with fresh ideas for unlocking new technologies and new markets. Putting it simple, Acemoglu and Robinson claim that when the conservative forces prevail, there is poverty, while it leads to progress and development when the forces of creative destruction are unleashed.

One of the most convincing examples in support of their viewpoint is the fact that there were various inventions of weaving machines and even of steam engines all over Europe before the industrial revolution. But these novelties were seen as threats to the existing economic order and were thus successfully suppressed by the ruling elites.

But why did industrialization pick up in England then?


EXCLUSIVE AND INCLUSIVE INSTITUTIONS

The authors not only describe the struggle between preservers and creative destroyers, but they also try to explain what determines the winner of this struggle. Here their concepts of “inclusive institutions” and “exclusive institutions” come into play.

Acemoglu and Robinson classify the economic and political institutions of a society on a scale of “inclusiveness”. The more inclusive institutions are, the more they reflect the economic interests of many members of the society (as opposed to the economic interests of just a small elite). In its most mature form, inclusive institutions are governed by a legal system that does not favor anybody, but treats everybody’s economic interests equally. Exclusive institutions, on the other hand, are directly controlled by a despot or by laws that foster the interests of the existing elite at the expense of the interests of those excluded from power.

The theory has many facets and twists that cannot be described here, but the above argument is what I would consider to be its centerpiece. To my mind, one can rightfully criticize the breadth of the domain to which this theory is applied, namely all societies throughout geography and time. Certainly, there were societies in history with institutions that were neither exclusive nor inclusive in the above sense. However, the general framework Acemoglu and Robinson propose is, despite its simplicity, amazingly powerful for interpreting history and even for making predictions.

For instance, Acemoglu and Robinson have a clear opinion about the future of “Chinese Capitalism”. Many economists are impressed by the Chinese achievements of the last twenty years, where mega-projects like airports and large water dams are carried out in breathtaking speed, and they believe that China will sooner or later overtake the West. Acemoglu and Robinson disagree. While also the exclusive institutions of China can generate some growth (otherwise there is nothing that can be exploited by an elite), they claim that in the middle-run these institutions will not allow for creative destruction. So, they predict, Chinese economic development will slow down. Already now, though generating high growth rates, the transformation of China neglects the economic interests of many members of the society, potentially causing unrest and upheaval – a negative side effect of exclusive institutions. After publication of their book, it was revealed that the elite of the Chinese communist party has accumulated huge riches, and just this week it became public that much of this money was harbored abroad. To my mind, this illustrates the exclusive character of the Chinese model.

For Acemoglu and Robinson, an open, democratic, and free society is not an impediment to long-run economic development, but rather its most important precondition.


AND GEORGIA?

If we subscribe to this theory, we should believe that Georgia has a bright future. Since the Rose Revolution of 2003, Georgia has done amazingly well in establishing inclusive institutions. These were so strong that the rulers who set up these institutions finally lost the elections and had to step down. Yet also the new political leaders of Georgia abide by the rules of democracy. While initially there were some calls to persecute the representatives of the old government, by and large a policy of revenge has been avoided.

Even more importantly, on the level of experts, technocrats, and bureaucrats, able people affiliated with the old government were not ousted. Almost all judges were left in office, maintaining an independent judiciary system, a crucial component of a system of “checks and balances”. In contrast, Acemoglu and Robinson describe how in South American countries the first act of new rulers is always to replace the judges at courts. Even President Roosevelt in the USA tried to get rid of a critical supreme court in the 1930s (to no avail). Though being democratic just since about 10 years, Georgian institutions seem to be very mature and much more inclusive than what can be seen in most of South America.

Therefore, after reading the book, I am now more optimistic about Georgia. If institutions determine the long-run economic success of a society, then Georgia is on the right track.

Rate this blog entry:
7 Comments

Related Posts

Comments

 
Guest - NP on Monday, 10 February 2014 14:02

Very interesting. One might argue that exclusion is now a characteristic increasingly shared not only by the Chinese communist model but also by the free market economies worldwide. One just needs to look at the increasing inequality and to the sharp contrast between the economic and social outcomes of the top 1% (or even 0.1%) of the world population and the rest to start worrying about the future consequences of the existing trends.

Very interesting. One might argue that exclusion is now a characteristic increasingly shared not only by the Chinese communist model but also by the free market economies worldwide. One just needs to look at the increasing inequality and to the sharp contrast between the economic and social outcomes of the top 1% (or even 0.1%) of the world population and the rest to start worrying about the future consequences of the existing trends.
Guest - LN on Monday, 10 February 2014 23:38

The idea of the theory discussed in the blog makes me optimistic too. Although, I would not agree with the author that Saakashvili's government was trying to establish inclusive institutions.

The idea of the theory discussed in the blog makes me optimistic too. Although, I would not agree with the author that Saakashvili's government was trying to establish inclusive institutions.
Guest - Eric on Tuesday, 11 February 2014 01:07

Thanks for this post, Florian!

Exclusive institutions, that do not allow for "create destruction" and stifle productivity and innovation are eventually swept aside by violent internal revolutions or conquest by competing nations. At its core, however, this theory is very old, except for the new inclusive/exclusive terminological trappings. For example, in Marxian terms, a forceful regime change occurs when the institutional framework (including the distribution of power) fails to adjust to the new economic realities. This is how Marx explained the "bourgeois" revolt against traditional aristocracies that failed (or were too slow) to "include" (incorporate) the interests of the new economic elite.

The authors' judgment on China is probably the weakest point in the book. I am not at all sure that Western liberal democracy is the only (or the best) institutional framework that can guarantee inclusion and creative destruction. For instance, I can think of "aristocratic" or "technocratic" arrangements ensuring pluralism and inclusion, such as those practiced by some countries and every successful business company.

Moreover, liberal democracy is not necessarily effective (and therefore appropriate) at every stage of economic development. Having performed the destructive function, "inclusive" democracies often give way to more "exclusive" regimes that are better at guaranteeing stability, law and order. At least for a while. This was the fate of liberal democracies in Europe of the 1920s and 1930s, and of many naive attempts at rapid democratization in Africa, Asia, Latin America, and most recently, in Eastern Europe and former Soviet Union.

Thanks for this post, Florian! Exclusive institutions, that do not allow for "create destruction" and stifle productivity and innovation are eventually swept aside by violent internal revolutions or conquest by competing nations. At its core, however, this theory is very old, except for the new inclusive/exclusive terminological trappings. For example, in Marxian terms, a forceful regime change occurs when the institutional framework (including the distribution of power) fails to adjust to the new economic realities. This is how Marx explained the "bourgeois" revolt against traditional aristocracies that failed (or were too slow) to "include" (incorporate) the interests of the new economic elite. The authors' judgment on China is probably the weakest point in the book. I am not at all sure that Western liberal democracy is the only (or the best) institutional framework that can guarantee inclusion and creative destruction. For instance, I can think of "aristocratic" or "technocratic" arrangements ensuring pluralism and inclusion, such as those practiced by some countries and every successful business company. Moreover, liberal democracy is not necessarily effective (and therefore appropriate) at every stage of economic development. Having performed the destructive function, "inclusive" democracies often give way to more "exclusive" regimes that are better at guaranteeing stability, law and order. At least for a while. This was the fate of liberal democracies in Europe of the 1920s and 1930s, and of many naive attempts at rapid democratization in Africa, Asia, Latin America, and most recently, in Eastern Europe and former Soviet Union.
Guest - Zahra on Tuesday, 11 February 2014 02:46

I have not read the book yet. But may be it is not totally right to attribute development to a single precondition. As we see from history in order to form countries the power of armies, religions, etc were used. in the process of development (as prof. Biermann noted in the meeting with German ambassador) as people were getting richer their preferences changed. At first, they had wealth which they should preserve, as a consequence wealth made them more powerful to influence the government (even governments were borrowing money from local elites) which ended up with democracy. now the question is what is the causality? did countries develop because they were more democratic or they became democratic because they already were rich?

I have not read the book yet. But may be it is not totally right to attribute development to a single precondition. As we see from history in order to form countries the power of armies, religions, etc were used. in the process of development (as prof. Biermann noted in the meeting with German ambassador) as people were getting richer their preferences changed. At first, they had wealth which they should preserve, as a consequence wealth made them more powerful to influence the government (even governments were borrowing money from local elites) which ended up with democracy. now the question is what is the causality? did countries develop because they were more democratic or they became democratic because they already were rich?
Guest - Adolfo (old ISETer) on Wednesday, 12 February 2014 03:03

I am very happy to leave a brief comment here, in an ISET blog. I really wish all of you are having a great academic year.
I think Zahra´s last question is really fundamental. Probably I am being narrow minded by focusing on the experience of my own European country (Spain), but my intuition is that some nations adopted more inclusive instutions once they had developed their own creative destruction.
That is, the main wave of sectoral and technological changes (creative destruction) were here implemented under exclusive, dictatorial regimes that curbed any possible resistance to reform.
Then, after the new productive organization (massive urbanization and industrialization, also connected with trade liberalization) was consolidated, people who were initially damaged by the changes (new rural-urban migrants) started also to enjoy from the higher growth of the national economy, which allowed the oligarchy to become more and more inclusive. Until the power advantage of the oligarchy became so small, that the oligrachy itself was somehow (not completely) diluted.
In other words, I believe that in some cases oligarchic regimes may be more conducive to creative destruction, as Eric does. Perhaps every historical example is different; I can not be sure there are clear patterns.

I am very happy to leave a brief comment here, in an ISET blog. I really wish all of you are having a great academic year. I think Zahra´s last question is really fundamental. Probably I am being narrow minded by focusing on the experience of my own European country (Spain), but my intuition is that some nations adopted more inclusive instutions once they had developed their own creative destruction. That is, the main wave of sectoral and technological changes (creative destruction) were here implemented under exclusive, dictatorial regimes that curbed any possible resistance to reform. Then, after the new productive organization (massive urbanization and industrialization, also connected with trade liberalization) was consolidated, people who were initially damaged by the changes (new rural-urban migrants) started also to enjoy from the higher growth of the national economy, which allowed the oligarchy to become more and more inclusive. Until the power advantage of the oligarchy became so small, that the oligrachy itself was somehow (not completely) diluted. In other words, I believe that in some cases oligarchic regimes may be more conducive to creative destruction, as Eric does. Perhaps every historical example is different; I can not be sure there are clear patterns.
Guest - Eric on Thursday, 13 February 2014 03:01

Old ISETer Adolfo, a great pleasure to have you back, even if only virtually! Very much agree with you point - dictatorial regimes can be quite good at cleaning the slate and preparing the ground for economic growth, followed by democratization and greater inclusivity. Spain is indeed a great example.

Old ISETer Adolfo, a great pleasure to have you back, even if only virtually! Very much agree with you point - dictatorial regimes can be quite good at cleaning the slate and preparing the ground for economic growth, followed by democratization and greater inclusivity. Spain is indeed a great example.
Guest - Giorgi Bakradze on Friday, 14 February 2014 15:46

Just nitpicking - wright is just an old English word for worker, you can have shipwrights and playwrights as well as wheelwrights :)

As for England and industrial revolution - luddite movement did try to prevent the technological progress, however the democratic institutes were already in place (not so democratic as today, obviously, but the important bits like court independence, freedom of speech, religious tolerance (most importantly) etc. were there) and this helped :)

Just nitpicking - wright is just an old English word for worker, you can have shipwrights and playwrights as well as wheelwrights :) As for England and industrial revolution - luddite movement did try to prevent the technological progress, however the democratic institutes were already in place (not so democratic as today, obviously, but the important bits like court independence, freedom of speech, religious tolerance (most importantly) etc. were there) and this helped :)
Already Registered? Login Here
Register
Guest
Saturday, 23 November 2024

Captcha Image

Our Partners