ISET

ISET Economist Blog

A blog about economics in the South Caucasus.

Georgian Pension Reform – an Experiment in Libertarian Paternalism?

Starting from October 1, 2017, a private retirement savings system will be launched in Georgia as part of a broader pension reform. This reform has been discussed by Nino Doghonadze and Yaroslava Babych in Decent Income in Old Age: Georgian Dream or Reality? on the ISET Economist. Today we will focus only on one very interesting aspect of the reform – the “opt-out” principle and its implementation in the Georgian realities.


WHAT’S IN THE “OPT-OUT”?

The proposed private retirement savings system is based on the “opt-out” principle, according to which all hired employees are automatically enrolled in the system, but have the opportunity to opt-out, should they wish to do so. In this sense, the libertarian ‘freedom of choice’ virtue is maintained – employees have the right to stay in or leave the system. At the same time, employers will not enjoy the same freedom – once a worker decides to stay in the system and pay his/her defined contribution (2% of the nominal salary), employers have no choice but match.


WHY “OUT” AND NOT “IN”? 

The “opt-out” principle can be a very powerful tool for policy makers to nudge citizens to make better choices. 

• First, it uses people’s natural inertia to encourage saving. Behavioral economics suggests that people tend to stick to defaults, i.e. the pre-selected options, and are usually too “lazy” to switch to anything else. The “opt-out” principle is thus a sneaky way for the policymakers to encourage desirable choices. Madrian and Shea (2001) studied the power of default options and inertia in case of savings behavior by employees in a large U.S. corporation. They find that, controlling for all other variables, the switch from active to automatic enrollment dramatically changed the savings behavior of employees.

• Second, automatic enrollment may generate the so-called “endowment effect” (a situation when person’s valuation of a good increases once s/he comes to own it). Once a person is already in the private pension system, s/he will tend to value it more than before. Thus, thanks to automatic enrollment, individuals who may otherwise not have enrolled may be convinced to stay in the system. 

If these behavior economics ideas are proven right in Georgia, the “opt-out” principle could go a long way towards solving the problem of low private savings in the country.


WILL “LIBERTARIAN PATERNALISM” SAVE GEORGIAN WOULD-BE-PENSIONERS? 

The proposed “opt-out” principle is an example of the so-called libertarian paternalism – a policy which affects people’s behavior while at the same time respecting their freedom of choice. The term was coined by Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein in their 2003 American Economic Review article. According to the authors, the “opt-out” principle is paternalistic in the sense that "it tries to influence choices in a way that will make choosers better off, as judged by themselves".

Indeed, for many young (and not so young) people, old age seems to be something that is far and away. Students or young adults do not usually think of retirement savings as their top priority because they find it difficult to imagine their old age or because they have unrealistic expectations about their sources of income in retirement. Gently nudging such forever young optimists to increase retirement savings may be in their own interest. 

In this respect it is interesting to look at the results of a recent survey which ISET helped conduct.

Age Depend on pension Depend on relatives Rent out real estate Save or will save in bank Will work in retirement age Do not know
18-33 7% 5% 22% 17% 23% 26%
34-49 14% 12% 19% 9% 27% 18%
50-65 28% 19% 9% 6% 26% 12%
Source: 2016 survey, done in cooperation with ISET

 

The table provides data on how people in three different age groups view potential sources of their retirement income. Among people who are very close to retirement (50-65) nearly a half (47%) realistically assess that they will depend on relatives or on meager state pensions.

In the youngest (18-33) age cohort, however, only 12% thought that they would depend on relatives or on publically-provided retirement benefits. Young Georgians optimistically plan to live on income from real estate rental (22%). They are also optimistic about their ability to save – 17% are planning to live off bank savings as compared to 9% and 6%, respectively, among those in the 34-49 and 50-65 age brackets.

These results suggest that Georgia’s young adults have rather unrealistic expectations as to their ability to generate retirement income from alternative sources, justifying a paternalistic action by the government.


THERE IS NO SUCH THING AS A FREE LUNCH

The libertarian “opt-out” principle comes at a price. In particular, it puts the entire pension reform at risk of failing to achieve its stated objectives if the majority of Georgians do indeed opt-out. 

What may force people out of the pension scheme? 

Low income. Clearly, in order to save one has to have sufficient income to at least cover the current household expenses.  If your salary is not enough to live on, the “opt-out” principle will not work. In this case the reform will cover only a small portion of employees with high incomes who may already be saving today. The Saving Behavior Assessment Survey in Georgia, conducted by ACT in 2011, showed that low income is the major obstacle for saving (70% of respondents). According to this study, an individual whose family’s monthly income exceeds 700 GEL is 2.9 times more likely to be saving than an individual whose family income falls short of 700 GEL. This study was focusing on general savings, but its findings are very relevant for analyzing retirement savings as well.

High unemployment. With unemployment standing at 12.4%, according to the latest available data (2014), Georgian employers have much more market power than their employees. The latter may opt-out of the system in order not to compromise their position at work. This is more likely to happen in low-productivity sectors and in small and medium size enterprises, which account for 36.9% of all hired employment in Georgia. Thus, the opt-out principle may not work for a very large portion of hired employees. Using the market power to “force” employees to opt-out of pension schemes is a problem in many developed countries, where this behavior is discouraged with high fines levied on employers. Georgian government is planning to introduce such fines and sanctions, but it is not clear whether such sanctions will be effective. Employers may use subtle methods to pressure their employees: discrimination at work or unfair dismissal may be hard to link to a person’s pension scheme choices. Employees are also quite likely to self-censor their behavior in order not to create problems for employers.

Burden of contributions. Obligatory employer contribution may be perceived as a tax levied on labor. Economic theory tells us that no matter who pays the tax, the tax burden is inevitably shared by both parties. Who will bear more of the burden and who will bear less of it will depend on labor supply and demand elasticities. Following this logic, we can expect that low skilled workers will bear a higher share of the burden by taking pay cuts and or being forced to opt-out of the pension scheme.

Trust towards the national currency. According to the ATC study, stability of the national currency was another important consideration in the savings behavior for 69% of respondents. Last year’s devaluation of the Georgian lari definitely caused many depositors to shift their money to dollar-denominated accounts. As pension savings will be held in GEL, a lack of trust in the national currency may prove a serious obstacle for the proposed pension reform scheme.

Finally, the degree of trust in the management of the new pension system will also be a key factor. A question in the ACT study about institutions preferred as potential deposit insurers can be used as a proxy for the level of trust people have in the government, at least when it comes to pensions. In the survey, 24% of respondents preferred to have a large Georgian bank as the deposit insurer, 21% preferred insurance offered by a foreign bank, 20% - by the Georgian government, and 12% by the National Bank of Georgia.

Based on this evidence we can say that as many as one fifth of the Georgian people still tend to trust the government with their savings, but it is not at all clear that this level of trust be sufficient to overcome all other obstacles and help people stay in the pension system. This is a question that the policy makers still need to answer.

Of those Georgians who save, only 6% are saving for retirement.

Rate this blog entry:
7 Comments

Related Posts

Comments

 
Simon Appleby on Sunday, 17 April 2016 12:43

The pension reform is inspired by the systems used in Australia, Hong Kong and Chile. In each case, they are mandatory systems with no opt-out. In Chile, a percentage of the first $25,000 of earnings is a mandatory contribution, and above that is voluntary.

https://fee.org/articles/how-we-privatized-social-security-in-chile/

The Australian system is mandatory, with a reduced rate of tax on workers earnings invested in superannuation funds. Worker contributes a percentage, employer contributes a bigger percentage, no opt-outs. Private pension funds/superannuation funds now are the dominant investment vehicle in Australia; it is now Australian workers who own the top 500 companies in the country rather than oligarchs or investment banks, via their super funds. The risk of investment purely in local currency assets is mitigated by a careful mix of local and offshore investments, and workers can choose what type of fund they want their assets in (fixed income/low risk, multicurrency/locally focussed etc.)

https://www.moneysmart.gov.au/superannuation-and-retirement/how-super-works

Upon retirement, workers can opt for fixed monthly payments, or take out their money as a lump sum and invest in in a self-managed superannuation fund. Investment properties for rental market are a common form of self-managed superannuation in Australia.

The issue of employers pressuring workers to opt out is an unfortunate one, and would be remedied by compulsion. The timing of reforms is critical; at a time when government is proposing abolishing corporate profits tax on reinvested income (a massive concession to industry), it would be the ideal time to introduce mandatory pension contributions from employers as a trade-off. Receive a big tax cut, give part of it away as increased employee on-costs, and industry is still ahead financially. Hopefully government will manage these negotiations prudently.

Georgia has a major problem with a lack of equity investment capital for mid-sized companies; there is a significant range of debt products available (very expensive and requiring more collateral than most other markets) but few VC or PE funds, and many are funded by IFIs rather than ordinary investors. Private pension contributions could be seeding such funds in addition to lower risk fixed-interest products and creating a virtuous circle of cheaper expansion capital, faster economic growth and better growth of investment savings for Georgian workers.

The pension reform is inspired by the systems used in Australia, Hong Kong and Chile. In each case, they are mandatory systems with no opt-out. In Chile, a percentage of the first $25,000 of earnings is a mandatory contribution, and above that is voluntary. https://fee.org/articles/how-we-privatized-social-security-in-chile/ The Australian system is mandatory, with a reduced rate of tax on workers earnings invested in superannuation funds. Worker contributes a percentage, employer contributes a bigger percentage, no opt-outs. Private pension funds/superannuation funds now are the dominant investment vehicle in Australia; it is now Australian workers who own the top 500 companies in the country rather than oligarchs or investment banks, via their super funds. The risk of investment purely in local currency assets is mitigated by a careful mix of local and offshore investments, and workers can choose what type of fund they want their assets in (fixed income/low risk, multicurrency/locally focussed etc.) https://www.moneysmart.gov.au/superannuation-and-retirement/how-super-works Upon retirement, workers can opt for fixed monthly payments, or take out their money as a lump sum and invest in in a self-managed superannuation fund. Investment properties for rental market are a common form of self-managed superannuation in Australia. The issue of employers pressuring workers to opt out is an unfortunate one, and would be remedied by compulsion. The timing of reforms is critical; at a time when government is proposing abolishing corporate profits tax on reinvested income (a massive concession to industry), it would be the ideal time to introduce mandatory pension contributions from employers as a trade-off. Receive a big tax cut, give part of it away as increased employee on-costs, and industry is still ahead financially. Hopefully government will manage these negotiations prudently. Georgia has a major problem with a lack of equity investment capital for mid-sized companies; there is a significant range of debt products available (very expensive and requiring more collateral than most other markets) but few VC or PE funds, and many are funded by IFIs rather than ordinary investors. Private pension contributions could be seeding such funds in addition to lower risk fixed-interest products and creating a virtuous circle of cheaper expansion capital, faster economic growth and better growth of investment savings for Georgian workers.
Eric Livny on Sunday, 17 April 2016 18:23

A very good point about timing, Simon! Indeed, combined with the corporate tax reform, the pension reform has better chances of passing politically while minimizing resistance by civil society and business organizations. The only downside is the fact the government may lack funds to contribute to the pension fund as a result of the corporate reform. Not sure about that. One would have to do appropriate calculations...

A very good point about timing, Simon! Indeed, combined with the corporate tax reform, the pension reform has better chances of passing politically while minimizing resistance by civil society and business organizations. The only downside is the fact the government may lack funds to contribute to the pension fund as a result of the corporate reform. Not sure about that. One would have to do appropriate calculations...
Simon Appleby on Sunday, 17 April 2016 19:20

In other jurisdictions, government makes no grants at all to private pension funds (unless talking about mandated employer contributions for civil servants); it would create a giant conflict of interest, being both a market regulator and an investor concurrently. It is workers and employers who contribute all the money, and government focusses on appropriate legislation and regulation.

In other jurisdictions, government makes no grants at all to private pension funds (unless talking about mandated employer contributions for civil servants); it would create a giant conflict of interest, being both a market regulator and an investor concurrently. It is workers and employers who contribute all the money, and government focusses on appropriate legislation and regulation.
Super User on Monday, 18 April 2016 18:42

You probably know that two years ago Armenia also introduced such reform system (before the system was PAYG). There was one difference compared to the proposed system in Georgia, namely that workers did not have the opt-out option. The system was mandatory for all employees who were born since 1977. One can argue whether it was correct to implement this system mandatory. And it turns out that many employees argue about that. You might also know about the huge protest against this new system. One can think of several reasons why employees in Armenia were against. One possible explanation is that workers were afraid of the uncertainty. They will sacrifice some money, invest in long term projects and in the end they do not know what will happen; any project has some probability of default. So, they thought that risk was high and wanted to avoid from that. This in my view is a typical behaviour of being risk averse. The other possible explanation could be that the majority of workers are not rich, therefore it is costly for them to save i.e they value todays money high. One can conduct an experiment to confirm whether this hypothesis is correct. Experimenter can ask the following question (clearly to labor force): You have two options, which one will you prefer: spend the last penny today or to save in bank account. Deposits are less risky investments (in case of small investments the probability is very low that in the end people will not get their accumulated investment; that is why I can claim that deposits are not risky investments) compared to investing through the pension system. So, by this experiment we can know whether this is the case in Armenia. The third possible explanation is that people (workers) simply do not trust the system. They might think once they agree on this system, it will be like they throw their money into the water. I think the first two possible explanations are the case in Armenia. Now, let us think from the governments point of view. Government can predict such behaviour of workers; so, allowing the workers to choose whether to participate in the system or not, will lead to very few number of participants. Being aware of this fact and because government cares about better standards of living of its population, when they will reach to retirement age, it could not give the opportunity to choose. In my opinion this is the explanation of mandatory implementation and was correct strategy by the government.
For the upcoming reform system in Georgia I can predict that in the beginning not everybody will be willing to join the system, again because the same factors that I mentioned above for Armenia can also be the case in Georgia. However, when workers see the first and hopefully positive results of their investment through the system, they will share this information with each other and consequently this will lead to more and more participants who will join the system.
And finally thank you authors for the interesting article.

You probably know that two years ago Armenia also introduced such reform system (before the system was PAYG). There was one difference compared to the proposed system in Georgia, namely that workers did not have the opt-out option. The system was mandatory for all employees who were born since 1977. One can argue whether it was correct to implement this system mandatory. And it turns out that many employees argue about that. You might also know about the huge protest against this new system. One can think of several reasons why employees in Armenia were against. One possible explanation is that workers were afraid of the uncertainty. They will sacrifice some money, invest in long term projects and in the end they do not know what will happen; any project has some probability of default. So, they thought that risk was high and wanted to avoid from that. This in my view is a typical behaviour of being risk averse. The other possible explanation could be that the majority of workers are not rich, therefore it is costly for them to save i.e they value todays money high. One can conduct an experiment to confirm whether this hypothesis is correct. Experimenter can ask the following question (clearly to labor force): You have two options, which one will you prefer: spend the last penny today or to save in bank account. Deposits are less risky investments (in case of small investments the probability is very low that in the end people will not get their accumulated investment; that is why I can claim that deposits are not risky investments) compared to investing through the pension system. So, by this experiment we can know whether this is the case in Armenia. The third possible explanation is that people (workers) simply do not trust the system. They might think once they agree on this system, it will be like they throw their money into the water. I think the first two possible explanations are the case in Armenia. Now, let us think from the governments point of view. Government can predict such behaviour of workers; so, allowing the workers to choose whether to participate in the system or not, will lead to very few number of participants. Being aware of this fact and because government cares about better standards of living of its population, when they will reach to retirement age, it could not give the opportunity to choose. In my opinion this is the explanation of mandatory implementation and was correct strategy by the government. For the upcoming reform system in Georgia I can predict that in the beginning not everybody will be willing to join the system, again because the same factors that I mentioned above for Armenia can also be the case in Georgia. However, when workers see the first and hopefully positive results of their investment through the system, they will share this information with each other and consequently this will lead to more and more participants who will join the system. And finally thank you authors for the interesting article.
Maka Chitanava on Monday, 18 April 2016 22:30

Dear Laura, thank you for providing such an interesting comment. Armenian experience is indeed very relevant for us. I believe mandatory pension system would have been met with the similar resistance from the public in Georgia because of the reasons you have stated.

Dear Laura, thank you for providing such an interesting comment. Armenian experience is indeed very relevant for us. I believe mandatory pension system would have been met with the similar resistance from the public in Georgia because of the reasons you have stated.
Florian Biermann on Wednesday, 20 April 2016 09:42

It all depends on the services and products the Georgian economy provides. This determines the wealth of a society. If the wealth of the society goes up because of good products and services, it is possible to sustain much more distorting social plans than paying just 2% in some pension fund. I think it would be smarter to first wait for the economy to develop, then impose social welfare measures on the economy. Otherwise, the welfare ambitions may stifle whatever little growth there is, and in the end it is just a redistribution of poverty.

It all depends on the services and products the Georgian economy provides. This determines the wealth of a society. If the wealth of the society goes up because of good products and services, it is possible to sustain much more distorting social plans than paying just 2% in some pension fund. I think it would be smarter to first wait for the economy to develop, then impose social welfare measures on the economy. Otherwise, the welfare ambitions may stifle whatever little growth there is, and in the end it is just a redistribution of poverty.
Guest - GiorgiJvarsheishvili on Saturday, 14 May 2016 02:38

The plan is to impose the default opt-out in all Georgia, right ?
The fact that in some US corporations and in some EU countries this kind of nudge worked in different contexts is not a guarantee that it will work in Georgia for the pension reform as well. Some possible reasons are discussed in this blog.

In general, better experimental strategy would be to make enrollment a default option only in some regions and observe if there are differences in enrollment rates... In other words, to make a proper experiment a control group is needed!

Or start with no default enrollment and then impose this general enrollment and observe if there is a difference in percentages of enrollment after the treatment...

Moreover, it is smarter to run such experiments in small towns first and see whether and how do such policies work. Then, if proven to be effective, apply them to the whole country.

Anyway, interesting contribution Maka and Yasya ! :)

The plan is to impose the default opt-out in all Georgia, right ? The fact that in some US corporations and in some EU countries this kind of nudge worked in different contexts is not a guarantee that it will work in Georgia for the pension reform as well. Some possible reasons are discussed in this blog. In general, better experimental strategy would be to make enrollment a default option only in some regions and observe if there are differences in enrollment rates... In other words, to make a proper experiment a control group is needed! Or start with no default enrollment and then impose this general enrollment and observe if there is a difference in percentages of enrollment after the treatment... Moreover, it is smarter to run such experiments in small towns first and see whether and how do such policies work. Then, if proven to be effective, apply them to the whole country. Anyway, interesting contribution Maka and Yasya ! :)
Already Registered? Login Here
Register
Guest
Saturday, 23 November 2024

Captcha Image

Our Partners